Sunday, 1 January 2017

Options De Politique Commerciale Stratégique Du Canada

Le Canada a besoin d'un plan B pour le commerce. D'une part, l'élection de Donald Trumps aux États-Unis signifie un chemin rocailleux pour le commerce dans le principal marché d'exportation du Canada. D'autre part, la façon dont le Canada s'est acquitté de la récente lutte pour conclure l'accord de l'Union européenne a créé une perception du Canada comme un partenaire de négociation fiable. Tandis que l'élection de Trumps défiera directement des éléments clés de l'environnement de commerce existant de Canadas, il ya aussi de nouvelles possibilités. La combinaison de ces deux facteurs constitue un argument convaincant pour une nouvelle politique visant à atténuer les nouveaux risques et à saisir de nouvelles opportunités. Les menaces de renégocier ou même de retrait de l'Accord de libre-échange nord-américain (ALENA) suscitent des inquiétudes, étant donné que plus de 76% des exportations du Canada, soit 90% des Albertas et plus de 50% des BC, se dirigent vers le sud. Peut-être dès son premier jour de mandat, Trump est également susceptible de déchirer Canadas seule autre carte sur la table pour diversifier son commerce l'accord Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP). Le PPT est la seule négociation commerciale active que le Canada ait actuellement avec l'Asie. Pour entrer en vigueur, le PPT doit être ratifié par six des membres du bloc qui doivent représenter 85% du PIB des membres. En d'autres termes, le Japon et les États-Unis doivent ratifier l'accord. Cela est allé d'un long coup aux États-Unis à aucune chance, avec l'élection Trumps. Trump a critiqué à maintes reprises l'accord, appelant cela un coup mortel pour la fabrication américaine et un désastre. Étant donné que Trumps a longtemps fait l'objet de dénonciations d'ententes commerciales et qu'il était capable de fonctionner unilatéralement sur le plan commercial, il s'attend à ce qu'il mène ses menaces sur le TPP et l'ALENA. Le gouvernement fédéral canadois doit maintenant réfléchir à un plan B post-TPP et prendre le contrôle du sort commercial du Canada. Le Canada a actuellement 11 accords de commerce extérieur complets. Parmi celles-ci, 5 seulement concernent des pays qui figurent parmi les 50 plus grandes économies du monde et 1 seulement l'économie asiatique. En fait, le PPT aurait donné au Canada 7 nouvelles relations commerciales en Asie. La perte du PPT mettra les entreprises canadiennes en situation de désavantage concurrentiel en Asie. Les Américains ont 14 accords commerciaux, dont 3 en Asie. Le Japon a 15, l'Australie a 11, Singapour a 14, la Malaisie 8, la Nouvelle-Zélande 11 et le Chili 21 accords commerciaux, dont 6 couvrent l'Asie. Le gouvernement Trudeau peut avoir le début d'un processus pour démarrer quelque chose avec la Chine. Il a fallu à l'Australie près d'une décennie pour conclure un accord superficiel avec les Chinois. Les bons accords commerciaux prennent des années, voire une décennie, pour se terminer. Une stratégie commerciale efficace, claire et ciblée n'est plus un luxe. Nous pensons que ce plan B devrait comprendre cinq éléments clés. Premièrement, tout plan à court terme doit commencer par la Chine. Le premier ministre Justin Trudeau et le premier ministre Li Keqiang ont tous deux fait des déclarations sur le désir de lancer les négociations pour un accord de libre-échange (ALE). Ces pourparlers devraient commencer dès que possible, car une entente conclue, sur la base de l'expérience Australias, sera vraisemblablement une décennie plus loin. Deuxièmement, le Canada devrait s'appuyer sur les négociations sur le PPT et signer des accords commerciaux bilatéraux avec les signataires du PPT chaque fois que possible, en commençant par Singapour. Puisque les négociations bilatérales avec Singapour étaient bien avancées avant qu'elles ne soient mises en attente pour les pourparlers TPP, un nouvel accord bilatéral pourrait être possible dans un ordre relativement court. Singapour est également la 35e économie mondiale et un centre important pour le commerce des services, ce qui est vital si le Canada doit équilibrer sa dépendance envers le commerce des produits de base. Le Canada devrait également envisager des accords bilatéraux avec d'autres parties au PPT de l'ANASE, y compris le Vietnam et la Malaisie. Ceux-ci seront probablement plus faciles à négocier et à conclure que les transactions avec d'autres États de l'Asie du Sud-Est, étant donné que bon nombre des questions clés ont été abordées dans le contexte du PPT. Chaque entente conclue permet aux entreprises canadiennes de s'implanter en Asie et d'accéder aux opportunités et aux préférences que les entreprises de pays sans accord de libre-échange n'ont pas. Cette stratégie consistant à conclure des accords avec des pays membres de l'ANASE avant de procéder à un éventuel accord commercial à l'échelle de l'ANASE est celle qui a été suivie par d'autres, y compris l'Union européenne. Les négociations avec un bloc de 10 membres vont être plus longues et difficiles, d'autant plus que le niveau d'intérêt des membres de l'ANASE dans les négociations avec le Canada est susceptible de varier. L'obtention de bons accords solides avec les principales économies de l'ASEAN faciliterait et améliorerait les négociations avec l'ensemble du bloc. L'Australie et la Nouvelle-Zélande sont toutes deux parties au PPT, mais négocier des accords bilatéraux avec elles pourrait présenter certains défis. L'Australie est un concurrent des Canadas dans de nombreux secteurs de marchandises, mais un accord moderne de deuxième génération avec l'Australie qui met l'accent sur l'investissement et le commerce des services pourrait ouvrir la porte à une plus grande coopération commerciale, joint-ventures et partenariats en Asie. Un accord similaire avec la Nouvelle-Zélande pourrait s'avérer encore plus bénéfique, mais ce ne serait probablement pas possible tant que le Canada n'aura pas modifié son régime de subventions aux produits laitiers. Un troisième élément de la stratégie canada ne serait pas une victoire rapide: il s'agirait de rouvrir les négociations avec le Japon, qui ont également été suspendues pendant les négociations du PPT. Les pourparlers bilatéraux avec le Japon ont été longs et difficiles et continueront sans doute à l'être. Bon nombre des concessions que le Japon a faites au Canada dans des secteurs critiques comme l'agriculture et l'automobile dans le contexte du PPT pourraient ne pas être à l'ordre du jour cette fois-ci. Sans la perspective d'obtenir un meilleur accès au marché américain, le Japon pourrait ne pas avoir beaucoup d'incitations à faire ces concessions au Canada. Le Japon a déjà accès au marché nord-américain par le biais de son accord de plusieurs décennies avec le Mexique, et le Japon après le TPP pourrait se concentrer sur la négociation avec les États-Unis. Mais maintenant, avec Donald Trump à la Maison Blanche et la possibilité pour le Japon de négocier un accord commercial avec les États-Unis maintenant douteux au mieux, négocier avec le Canada devrait être plus attrayant pour le Japon. Quatrièmement, le plan B de Canadas ne devrait pas investir ses ressources limitées dans les négociations avec les pays où un gain n'est pas probable à moyen terme ou où le rendement de l'investissement sera trop faible pour valoir l'effort pour l'instant. Une négociation commerciale qui ne semble pas logique pour l'investissement actuel de ressources est une négociation à plus long terme avec l'Inde. Bien qu'il soit utile de tenir des négociations sur des secteurs particuliers, il ne vaut pas le temps de conclure un accord plus large. Dans le domaine de la réduction tarifaire, l'offre d'ouverture indienne est médiocre. Il semble également que l'Inde manque de l'intérêt et de la volonté politique de négocier et de vendre une entente avec le Canada à la maison. Le Canada a déjà vu ce film auparavant, dans les tentatives infructueuses de négocier un accord commercial avec le Brésil, un pays qui n'avait aucun intérêt réel pour le Canada, même après que le gouvernement canadien eut manifestement l'intention d'atteindre ce pays. Le Canada doit concentrer ses ressources et ses efforts sur des négociations qui apporteront des avantages réels aux entreprises canadiennes. Cinquièmement, dans toute cette attention accordée à l'Asie, le Canada ne doit pas oublier l'importance de ce côté du Pacifique, et surtout du marché américain. Avec Donald Trump à la Maison Blanche et l'anti-commerce croissant, déchirer le sentiment de l'ALENA aux États-Unis, le Canada devra consacrer plus de temps et de ressources à conserver sa part de marché et à combattre les irritants commerciaux avec les Américains. Les ressources, au niveau fédéral et provincial, devront augmenter et devraient à peu près égaler ce qui est mis en ouvrant des marchés en Asie. Enfin, des ressources et une attention sérieuses doivent être consacrées à l'éducation et à la promotion du commerce au Canada. Bien que les sondages récents montrent que la majorité des Canadiens ont généralement des opinions favorables à l'égard des accords commerciaux et commerciaux, le moyen le plus sûr de perdre cette majorité est de faire ce que les Américains ont fait: ne pas défendre proactivement le commerce et permettre que la désinformation reste incontestée. Il est important d'avoir une discussion équilibrée sur les avantages et les coûts des accords commerciaux. Cela signifie reconnaître leurs impacts négatifs potentiels et proposer des réponses politiques réalistes et crédibles. Notre politique commerciale ne peut pas être ambitieuse ou progressive pour un engagement autour du Pacifique, elle doit avant tout être réaliste. Au fur et à mesure que le Canada élaborera une stratégie intelligente et judicieuse sur le commerce, il devra réfléchir à ses priorités et examiner ce qui est souhaitable autant que possible et ce qui est nécessaire autant que ce qui est politiquement opportun. L'horloge tourne. Photo: Pete Spiro Shutterstock Avez-vous quelque chose à dire sur l'article que vous venez de lire? Faites partie de la discussion sur les options politiques et envoyez votre propre soumission. Voici un lien sur la manière de le faire. Souhaitez-vous ragir cet article Joignez-vous aux dbats d Options politiques et soumettez-nous votre texte en suivant ces directives. Sujets intéressants Carlo Dade est directeur du Centre de politique commerciale et d'investissement de la Fondation Canada-Ouest. Il est également membre du Conseil mexicain des relations extérieures et membre associé principal du programme des Amériques au Centre d'études stratégiques et internationales à Washington, DC. Deborah Elms est directrice exécutive du Asian Trade Centre (ATC) à Singapour. L'ATC collabore avec les gouvernements et les entreprises afin de créer de meilleures politiques commerciales en Asie en menant des activités de recherche, de formation et de plaidoyer sur les questions commerciales dans toute la région. Patrick Leblond 1 er juillet 2010 À la mi-janvier 2010, À Bruxelles pour participer au deuxième cycle de négociations sur l'Accord économique et commercial global (AECG) entre le Canada et l'Union européenne (UE). Plus tard, en avril, c'est à Ottawa que se tiendra le troisième tour de négociation. S'il est signé, l'AECG serait le deuxième accord commercial bilatéral jamais négocié par le Canada, après le libre-échange avec les États-Unis. Pourtant, contrairement aux accords de libre-échange avec notre voisin du Sud, l'AECG a suscité peu de discussions et de débats publics. Tout le monde attend peut-être que les négociations se terminent avant de prendre position sur l'accord. Ou peut-être personne ne se passionne pour l'Europe. Quoi qu'il en soit, une attitude d'attente et de souci serait regrettable compte tenu des ramifications économiques et politiques potentielles de cet accord. Avant de discuter des implications du CETA8217 pour le Canada, il est utile de comprendre comment nous sommes arrivés ici en premier lieu. Tout a commencé à l'automne 2006, lorsque l'ancien ambassadeur de l'UE au Canada, Dorian Prince, a fait savoir en privé, ainsi que publiquement, que le Canada avait une chance de s'ouvrir au Canada si celui-ci était intéressé par un partenariat économique plus profond avec le UE. Parallèlement, l'Allemagne, qui devait tenir la présidence tournante de six mois de l'UE au cours du premier semestre de 2007, a fait savoir qu'elle souhaitait promouvoir une coopération économique plus étroite avec les États-Unis et peut-être avec le Canada. Avec le plateau commercial régional en Amérique du Nord et en Europe, les négociations multilatérales du cycle de Doha et les accords de libre-échange bilatéraux avec la Chine, les dirigeants politiques et économiques des deux côtés de l'Atlantique cherchaient des moyens d'améliorer les débouchés commerciaux. C'est ainsi que la vieille idée de l'Accord de libre-échange transatlantique a été rétablie. Mais c'est à ce moment-là que le premier ministre du Québec, Jean Charest, a lancé en janvier 2007, lors du Forum économique mondial de Davos, un partenariat économique entre le Canada et l'UE selon lequel la balle CETA était vraiment lancée. Lors de leur sommet annuel à Berlin le 4 juin 2007, le Canada et l'UE ont accepté de coopérer à une étude conjointe pour évaluer les coûts et les avantages d'un partenariat économique plus étroit entre eux. Lorsque nous parlons d'un accord de partenariat économique, il est à noter que nous ne parlons pas seulement d'un accord de libre-échange traditionnel tel que l'ALENA, où les droits de douane sur le commerce des biens et des services sont éliminés. Nous parlons aussi d'un accord commercial de deuxième génération où l'accent est mis sur les obstacles non tarifaires tels que les normes, les procédures et les règlements. Celles-ci sont devenues la principale source d'entraves au commerce, puisque les tarifs sont maintenant assez bas, en particulier ceux entre les pays riches en raison de l'Accord général sur les tarifs douaniers et le commerce (GATT) et de l'Organisation mondiale du commerce (OMC). Par exemple, en 2007, les marchandises canadiennes ont fait face à un tarif moyen de 2,2 pour cent lorsqu'elles sont entrées dans l'UE, alors qu'à cette époque, les marchandises européennes ont été touchées avec un tarif moyen de 3,5 pour cent pour entrer sur le marché canadien. L'étude conjointe a été publiée un peu plus d'un an plus tard lors du prochain sommet Canada-UE qui s'est tenu à Québec le 17 octobre 2008. Il a conclu qu'une entente de partenariat économique de deuxième génération permettrait au Canada d'accroître ses exportations de Des biens et des services à l'UE de 8,5 milliards 8211 millions de lires (12,5 milliards d'euros), tandis qu'en retour, l'UE pourrait augmenter ses exportations vers le Canada de 1 7 milliards (25 milliards). Le rapport indiquait également que le PIB de l'UE et du Canada augmenterait de 1,6 milliard (17,1 milliards) et de 8,2 milliards (12,1 milliards), respectivement (voir le graphique 1 pour les échanges récents entre le Canada et l'UE). Bien que ces montants ne soient pas négligeables en termes absolus, ils ne représentent que 0,08 pour cent et 0,77 pour cent du PIB européen et canadien, respectivement. Ainsi, les gains économiques escomptés sont légers par rapport à la taille des économies européenne et canadienne. Bien sûr, les avantages d'un tel accord ne seraient pas répartis uniformément entre les résidents canadiens. Selon l'étude conjointe, au Canada, les secteurs des métaux, du transport et de l'équipement électronique verraient les gains économiques les plus importants découlant d'un tel accord. On peut également supposer que les provinces qui commercent plus avec l'UE, comme le Québec, tireraient la plupart des avantages économiques. En plus d'examiner les répercussions économiques et commerciales d'un accord de partenariat économique, l'étude conjointe a tenté d'identifier les obstacles actuels au commerce et à l'investissement entre le Canada et l'UE. Par exemple, chaque province canadienne a des règlements différents, ce qui signifie des exigences différentes pour la reconnaissance des qualifications professionnelles, des licences d'exercice et des accréditations. Ces réglementations divergentes constituent un obstacle à la mobilité de la main-d'œuvre et ont un impact négatif sur le commerce des services. Cela signifie qu'à l'heure actuelle, les ingénieurs européens qui veulent offrir leurs services au Canada doivent se conformer à 10 règlements différents. C'est déraisonnable. L'étude conjointe indique que tout accord entre le Canada et l'UE devrait résoudre des problèmes comme celui-ci, de sorte que les Européens seraient confrontés à un marché unique au Canada comme ils le sont en Europe. Les marchés publics constituent un autre obstacle au commerce canadien. À l'heure actuelle, les entreprises européennes se considèrent comme handicapées lorsque les gouvernements provinciaux et territoriaux lancent des appels d'offres pour la fourniture de biens et de services. Par exemple, dans le cas du métro de Montréal, le contrat a d'abord été attribué à Bombardier Transport, et la société européenne Alstom n'a même pas été invitée à soumettre une offre. Bien que l'OMC exige que ses membres traitent les entreprises étrangères sur un pied d'égalité avec leurs sociétés nationales lorsqu'il s'agit de conclure des ententes avec le gouvernement, ces règles s'appliquent uniquement au gouvernement fédéral au Canada, elles ne s'appliquent pas aux gouvernements provinciaux, territoriaux ou municipaux . Le Canada a obtenu cette exemption de l'OMC, mais l'exclusion est devenue l'objet de nombreuses critiques au sein de l'UE. (L'entente récemment annoncée entre le Canada et les États-Unis sur la disposition Buy America dans la mesure de la relance budgétaire touche à la même question.) Les Européens ont clairement dit que le Canada devra abandonner cette exclusion si les négociations d'un accord de partenariat économique sont Pour avoir une chance de réussir. L'étude conjointe a permis de cerner plusieurs autres exemples de ce genre et a tenté de quantifier ce que chacun coûterait en termes d'occasions de commerce entre le Canada et l'UE. Il a également souligné plusieurs domaines dans lesquels le Canada et l'UE pourraient tirer parti d'une plus grande collaboration: la science et la technologie, l'énergie, l'environnement, les transports, les douanes et l'éducation. Cette collaboration accrue permettrait d'améliorer l'échange d'idées et de bonnes pratiques, dans le but ultime d'amener plus de gens et d'entreprises des deux côtés de l'Atlantique à faire des affaires les unes avec les autres. Au sommet de Québec, suite à l'approbation des conclusions de l'étude conjointe8217, les parties ont convenu d'entreprendre une étude préliminaire pour le Canada et l'UE afin de négocier éventuellement un accord de partenariat économique. Les résultats de cet exercice de détermination de la portée ont été publiés en mars 2009 et un accord de démarrage des négociations a été finalisé lors du sommet Canada-UE qui s'est tenu à Prague le 6 mai 2009. Le premier cycle de négociations a eu lieu à Ottawa en octobre 2009. Le second tour s'est tenu à Bruxelles en janvier 2010, le troisième étant retourné à Ottawa trois mois plus tard. Jusqu'à présent, il semble que les négociations avancent bien, bien que les questions difficiles doivent encore être abordées. Quels sont les enjeux de la table de négociation En dépit de la nature de la deuxième génération de l'accord, l'élimination des droits de douane sur les marchandises échangées demeure un enjeu majeur. Selon l'étude conjointe, un quart à un tiers des avantages découlant d'un accord de partenariat viendrait de se débarrasser de ces obligations. Les deux parties ont clairement précisé qu'aucune ligne tarifaire, même sur les produits agricoles, n'est exclue a priori des négociations. Reste à savoir combien de temps faudra-t-il aux lobbies agricoles politiquement puissants des deux côtés de l'Atlantique pour sortir des négociations les barrières commerciales agricoles et d'autres distorsions (par exemple les subventions à l'exportation et les mécanismes de gestion de l'offre). Les obstacles au commerce des services font également partie des priorités des négociations. Encore une fois, l'exercice de détermination de la portée a permis qu'aucun secteur ne soit exclu a priori. L'objectif est d'améliorer l'accès aux marchés et d'éliminer la discrimination en faveur des prestataires nationaux. Par exemple, un accord impliquerait la reconnaissance mutuelle des qualifications professionnelles. Cela permettrait aux entreprises d'envoyer plus facilement des Canadiens à l'Europe (ou aux Européens au Canada) pour travailler avec des filiales et des partenaires commerciaux. L'intention générale ici est de s'appuyer sur les deux partenaires dans le cadre des engagements existants de l'OMC sous l'égide de l'Accord général sur le commerce des services (AGCS). Le Canada et l'UE souhaitent aussi éliminer les barrières non tarifaires dans d'autres régions. Par exemple, en s'appuyant sur l'Accord de l'OMC sur les mesures sanitaires et phytosanitaires, ainsi que sur l'Accord vétérinaire Canada-UE, les normes et réglementations sanitaires qui restreignent le commerce des biens et services devront être éliminées par l'harmonisation ou la reconnaissance mutuelle. En outre, il existe un besoin de coopération transatlantique en matière d'évaluation de la conformité. La même logique s'applique aux procédures douanières où, par exemple, les deux parties devront coopérer afin d'assurer le respect des dispositions relatives aux règles d'origine. Dans ce cas, l'AECG s'appuierait sur l'Accord de coopération douanière et d'assistance mutuelle en matière douanière existant entre le Canada et la Communauté européenne (à savoir l'UE). Enfin, en ce qui concerne les obstacles non tarifaires, les négociations viseront également à faciliter l'accès au marché et à mettre en place des mesures de non-discrimination en matière d'investissement et de marchés publics, ainsi que d'accroître la protection et l'application des droits de propriété intellectuelle, Accord sur les droits de propriété intellectuelle. Les négociations de l'AECG devraient également aborder un mécanisme de règlement des différends, la politique de la concurrence, la circulation des personnes, le travail et l'environnement. L'Accord de libre-échange entre le Canada et les États-Unis était le premier accord bilatéral de libre-échange visant à placer le règlement des différends au centre des négociations. Depuis lors, la plupart des accords bilatéraux et multilatéraux de libéralisation des échanges prévoient de tels mécanismes pour rendre les accords plus efficaces. En ce qui concerne la politique de la concurrence, on reconnaît de plus en plus que les aides d'État et d'autres formes d'intervention de l'État dans l'économie (par exemple la réglementation des monopoles) peuvent fausser le caractère concurrentiel des marchés et créer des obstacles au commerce et à l'investissement. L'AECG inclurait également des mesures visant à faciliter la circulation temporaire de main-d'œuvre à des fins de commerce et d'investissement, ce qui pourrait signifier des visas spéciaux ou des permis de travail pour les Canadiens (européens) travaillant dans l'UE (Canada) depuis moins d'un an. Enfin, comme c'est le cas dans la plupart des accords commerciaux bilatéraux auxquels participent actuellement les pays riches, les négociateurs de l'AECG mettront en place des mécanismes de coopération prévoyant que les lois et les normes canadiennes et européennes en matière de travail et d'environnement ne favorisent ni le commerce ni l'investissement. Des accords parallèles sur l'environnement et la main-d'oeuvre comme ceux de l'ALENA pour assouvir les Américains8217 craignent que, avec des lois et des normes de travail moins strictes et des normes environnementales, le Mexique suce leurs emplois au sud de la frontière. Il est clair que le Canada et l'UE ont de grandes ambitions pour l'AECG. Si les négociations aboutissent et qu'un accord est conclu, l'AECG pourrait servir de modèle au reste du monde pour ce qui est des accords commerciaux préférentiels de deuxième génération ou de prochaine génération (ceux où l'élimination des tarifs n'est pas la principale préoccupation). Il pourrait même servir de prélude ou d'essai pour un accord transatlantique plus large qui inclurait les États-Unis, qui pourrait constituer l'objectif ultime de l'Union européenne et dont le Canada ne s'opposerait certainement pas. Mais quelles sont les conditions du succès? La condition essentielle est que les provinces participent activement aux négociations (c'est pourquoi la délégation canadienne à Bruxelles en janvier 2010 était composée d'une centaine de personnes) et s'engagent de façon crédible dans l'entente. C'est parce que les provinces seront finalement responsables de la mise en œuvre de la plupart des dispositions de l'accord (celles qui traitent des obstacles non tarifaires). Bien que les droits de douane (droits de douane) relèvent de la compétence fédérale, de nombreux secteurs, comme l'agriculture, le travail, la santé et l'environnement, relèvent soit des compétences provinciales exclusives, soit exclusives. Le pire serait que l'UE consacre du temps et de l'énergie à la négociation de l'AECG pour savoir que bon nombre de ces dispositions ne sont pas appliquées ou mises en œuvre par certaines ou toutes les provinces. C'est pourquoi l'UE a fait de la participation active des pays dans les négociations une condition sine qua non pour le début des négociations. Il fallait aussi que les provinces signent un accord politique pour ne pas renier un accord qu'elles acceptent. L'UE continue de négocier un AECG avec le Canada. C'est parce que la validité juridique de l'engagement des provinces dans la mise en œuvre d'un accord n'est pas claire. Quel type de recours juridique l'UE aurait-elle si une ou plusieurs provinces refusaient de mettre en œuvre certaines parties de l'accord? Puisque je ne suis pas juriste, je ne peux pas répondre à cette question, mais je suis sûr que les négociateurs de l'UE tentent de mettre autant de garanties Possible dans l'accord (en particulier dans le mécanisme de règlement des différends) afin de faire face à ce risque. Ces garanties sont tout aussi importantes pour le Canada. La dernière chose que le Canada veut, c'est que l'UE impose des sanctions ad hoc en matière de commerce et d'investissement parce qu'une province ne met pas en œuvre les dispositions de l'AECG. Ce qui veut dire que ces remèdes ne viseraient que la province non coopérative En fin de compte, la défection par une province pourrait démêler l'ensemble de l'affaire. De telles incertitudes seraient très mauvaises pour les entreprises. Si l'objectif de CETA8217 est d'augmenter le commerce et l'investissement, alors il serait préférable de supprimer autant d'incertitude que possible à l'avance, puisque les affaires abhorre les aspirations juridiques. Sinon, pour paraphraser W. P. Kinsella, même si nous le construisons, ils ne peuvent pas venir. S'agissant de la principale préoccupation de Michael Hart8217 à l'égard de l'AECG, l'autre condition importante pour les négociations fructueuses est que l'entente ne doit pas nuire à la position concurrentielle des entreprises canadiennes sur le marché américain. Cela signifie que toute tentative d'harmonisation des lois, des règles, des normes, des règlements et des procédures ne peut se faire au détriment de la relation économique entre le Canada et les États-Unis. Il s'agit d'une ligne rouge pour le Canada. Si les Européens pensent que l'AECG est un tremplin vers un accord transatlantique plus large avec les États-Unis, on pourrait considérer que cette condition n'est pas très restrictive. Il peut être naïf de penser, cependant, que les Européens seront prêts à faire des compromis à court terme en ce qui concerne l'AECG afin d'augmenter les chances d'un accord avec les Américains à long terme. En tout état de cause, tout accord transatlantique mettant en cause les États-Unis est peu probable avant 2021, après les élections présidentielles de 2020. En plus des avantages économiques mentionnés ci-dessus, l'AECG pourrait offrir au Canada la meilleure occasion de créer un marché commun à l'intérieur de ses frontières, ce qui rend réelles les ambitions associées aux provinces8217 Accord sur le commerce intérieur. Il est ironique qu'un État comme le Canada n'ait pas d'intégration économique interne alors que l'UE, avec 27 États membres, le fait (même si elle est loin d'être parfaite). Si toutes les 10 provinces se sont engagées à l'AECG, elles devront harmoniser ou reconnaître mutuellement les lois, les règles, les normes et les procédures non seulement avec l'Europe, mais aussi entre elles. À l'heure actuelle, seules l'Alberta et la Colombie-Britannique ont signé un accord interne complet sur le commerce, l'investissement et la mobilité de la main-d'œuvre (en vigueur depuis avril 2007), que la Saskatchewan a décidé de joindre en mars 2009. L'Ontario et le Québec sont en train de développer un partenariat économique et ils ont signé l'Accord de commerce et de coopération Ontario-Québec en septembre 2009. Il est à espérer que les négociations de l'AECG feront en sorte que ces ententes de partenariat économique soient compatibles entre elles. Fédération canadienne. L'AECG souligne également la faiblesse institutionnelle des relations fédérales-provinciales lorsqu'il s'agit de négocier des ententes internationales touchant les juridictions provinciales. En fait, le Canada n'a pas de mécanisme formel de négociation de ces accords, tandis que l'UE a le Conseil des ministres, le Parlement européen et la Commission européenne, ainsi que des règles très élaborées pour négocier et ratifier les accords internationaux. La faiblesse du Canada à cet égard a été clairement mise en évidence lors de la Conférence des Nations Unies sur le changement climatique qui s'est tenue à Copenhague en décembre dernier, lorsque le Québec a agi indépendamment du gouvernement fédéral. Le Conseil de la Fédération, créé en 2003, est une base prometteuse pour le développement d'un mécanisme institutionnel de coordination des positions de négociation des provinces et des territoires. En tant que tel, il pourrait devenir comme le Conseil des ministres dans l'UE, mais il doit aller plus loin qu'une réunion des premiers ministres deux fois par an. Les ministres de divers ministères devraient se réunir régulièrement entre les premiers ministres, comme le Conseil des ministres de l'UE 8217 se réunit chaque semaine, sur les affaires étrangères, les transports, l'environnement, etc. De plus, comme en Europe, le Conseil de la Fédération peut Profitent de la présence de représentants permanents des provinces pour préparer des réunions de ministres et d'interagir avec des représentants du gouvernement fédéral sur des questions touchant toutes les provinces et les territoires, comme la négociation d'accords internationaux impliquant des juridictions provinciales. En fait, il est surprenant que le Conseil de la Fédération ne soit pas utilisé comme tremplin institutionnel pour que les provinces participent aux négociations de l'AECG. Au lieu de cela, chaque province a décidé d'envoyer son propre représentant. Dans quelle mesure ces négociateurs provinciaux coordonnent-ils leurs positions à l'avance reste toutefois peu clair, il est probable qu'il y a peu de coordination, voire aucune, entre ces deux pays. Bien qu'il soit peut-être trop tard pour utiliser le contexte des négociations de l'AECG pour développer un mécanisme institutionnel efficace pour coordonner les positions fédérales, provinciales et éventuellement territoriales du Canada dans les négociations internationales, les dirigeants politiques du Canada ne peuvent pas attendre la prochaine série de négociations internationales pour concevoir Un tel mécanisme de coordination. Avec la mondialisation poussant de plus en plus au niveau international la gouvernance de questions qui étaient autrefois considérées comme étant exclusivement nationales et donc provinciales, le Canada doit être institutionnellement préparé à prendre une position commune solide et à s'engager à tous les niveaux du gouvernement à conclure des accords internationaux. Autrement, nous risquons de perdre notre capacité d'interagir économiquement et politiquement au niveau international. Cet article est basé sur une présentation qu'il a donnée à Carleton University8217s Centre d'études européennes en Novembre 2009. Hot TopicsCanada8217s Stratégique Options de politique commerciale e-mail Partager le lien on-irpp. org2eo0P4I Avec les négociations commerciales multilatérales bloquées, une reprise lente aux États-Unis et de résurgence La croissance des marchés émergents tels que l'Inde et la Chine, la question stratégique de savoir si la politique commerciale du Canada doit être axée sur l'approfondissement des liens commerciaux en Amérique du Nord ou plus activement sur les marchés ailleurs est devenue plus pressante. Certains affirment que la géographie et la taille signifient que la part du lion des avantages commerciaux proviendra inévitablement des États-Unis, tandis que d'autres notent qu'un foyer continental ignore les trois quarts de l'économie mondiale (une grande partie croissant plus vite que l'Amérique du Nord) à son péril . Malgré les revendications des deux parties, il existe relativement peu de données empiriques sur lesquelles les juger. Cette étude cherche à combler ce vide en comparant les avantages économiques de la mise en œuvre d'une union douanière nord-américaine avec ceux d'une part croissante de la part du Canada dans les échanges avec l'Europe et les grandes économies émergentes. Contrairement aux analyses plus traditionnelles de la diversification, l'étude de Patrick Georges et Marcel Merette examine l'effet potentiel des tendances démographiques dans certains pays sur les termes de l'échange du Canada et montre que cet effet est suffisamment important pour être pris en compte dans l'élaboration des politiques commerciales. Les avantages de l'approfondissement de l'intégration continentale par l'intermédiaire d'une union douanière (qui éliminerait les règles d'origine coûteuses et réduirait le coût des biens intermédiaires) sont relativement faibles. La négociation d'une union douanière au milieu des années 1990 dans le cadre du remplacement ou de la modernisation de l'ALENA aurait fait croître le PIB canadien d'environ 1 p. 100 (environ 15 milliards de dollars par an). Mais si nous le faisions aujourd'hui, les avantages seraient inférieurs à la moitié, principalement parce que les réductions tarifaires multilatérales convenues dans les années 1990 ont réduit les avantages des préférences de l'ALÉNA. The economic benefits of diversification are potentially larger than those of deepening North American integration, so long as partners are selected carefully. Canada should build up trade links with nations with relatively young populations to take advantage of demographically driven improvements in its terms of trade as well as strong economic growth in those nations. Diversifying 10 percentage points of Canada8217s trade from the United States to India, for example, would boost domestic consumption per capita by almost 5 percent in 2050 relative to its baseline level. Trade diversification to the European Union, on the other hand, could actually reduce consumption relative to the status quo. The tough question is, of course, how to diversify trade. Georges and Merette see this as a longterm proposition by which cultural ties, trust and networks can pave the way for trade missions and eventual preferential trade agreements. As observed by Head (2007), Canada8217s debate on trade policy typically centres on two questions, one strategic and one tactical. The strategic question is whether Canada should diversify its trade pattern away from the United States, or whether it should pursue deeper continental integration. The tactical question is how we should conduct our chosen strategy. Strategic and tactical questions are clearly nested. For example, Canada could engage more with the rest of the world through multilateral trade negotiations, formal preferential trade agreements (PTAs) with selected countries, ad hoc trade promotion (e. g. Team Canada missions) or a unilateral decision to reduce or eliminate trade barriers (Helliwell 2002 Dobson 2006 Head 2007). Canada could pursue deeper integration with the United States by reducing the burden of crossing the border, harmonizing regulatory procedures and standards, negotiating a common external tariff and customs union, simplifying NAFTA rules of origin, liberalizing the remaining restrictions on US direct investment in Canada and the movement of labour, and negotiating agreements to curb US trade remedy laws (e. g. Dobson 2002 Harris 2003 Goldfarb 2003 Hart 2007 Mandel-Campbell 2008 Georges 2010). Figure 1 provides a convenient starting point for the strategic trade policy debate in Canada by illustrating trade with the United States as a share of total Canadian trade. The United States is Canada8217s largest trading partner both as an export market and as a supplier. The strategic positions on Canadian trade policy are easily foreseen from this figure. On the one hand, some advocate an almost exclusive focus on the United States. For example, Hart (2007) claims that more than ever, the two-way movement of goods and services across the Canada-US border is Canada8217s economic lifeline (429). He says, Engagement with our southern neighbour is the indispensable foundation of any Canadian policy to maximize benefits from international trade and investments (418-19). On the other hand, some politicians and commentators argue, often during US recessions, that the Canadian economy is too exposed to the US business cycle, that there is risk involved in having so many eggs in the American basket, and that alternative markets must be developed in order to diversify away from the US economy. This argument, which unsurprisingly gained favour at the start of the 2008-09 US recession, is far from new there have been attempts to reduce Canada8217s trade dependence on the United States by seeking closer economic links elsewhere. For example, in 1957, Prime Minister John Diefenbaker announced that Canada would shift 15 percent of its trade from the United States to Great Britain. In the 1970s, the Trudeau government searched for closer economic links with the European Community. Both initiatives failed to achieve their goals. Many participants in this strategic debate about whether or not to diversify trade away from the United States typically dismiss, even mock, the proposals of others while predicting huge potential gains from their favoured option, without providing much in the way of empirical evidence. Indeed, empirical evidence is rare and, when it exists, it does not necessarily corroborate these claims. For example, much has been written about how deeper integration will further reduce the cost of cross-border trade and should theoretically increase access to North American markets and spur economic growth in Canada. But there are virtually no quantitative studies of how much incremental economic benefit would result from additional integration. Pastor (2008, 94) ironically refers to the North American game of Scrabble which, since 2001, has consisted of the leaders of Canada, Mexico and the United States meeting periodically to spell new acronyms that purport to be initiatives, and then promptly discarding them. (See figure 2 for some of these initiatives.) He notes that if one measures progress by examining the growth in trade, the reduction in wait times at the borders and the public support for integration, all of these initiatives have failed miserably. What is lacking, in Pastor8217s view, is a North American vision based on the simple premise that each country benefits from its neighbors8217 success and each is diminished by their problems or setbacks. Such a vision stimulates a new consciousness, a new way of thinking about one8217s neighbors and about the continental agenda so that Americans, Canadians, and Mexicans can be nationals and North American at the same time. This vision of North America, according to Pastor, could evolve from a customs union and a common team of customs and border guards at the continental perimeters, thereby eliminating the costly and cumbersome rule-of-origin regulations and allowing all legitimate goods to move seamlessly across the borders. To do this, the three governments would need to negotiate a common external tariff. Given the size and proximity of the United States, bilateral issues will always be on the Canadian policy agenda. However, as Head (2007, 446) points out, the important issue with respect to the strategic question and the best allocation of trade negotiation resources concerns our effort on the margin: Would the allocation of more resources to deeper integration with the U. S. generate larger marginal net benefits than a similar resource allocation directed at broader integration with the rest of the world In his opinion, Canada cannot maximize its benefits from international trade by disengaging from the three-quarters of the global economy that is outside the United States. Helliwell (2002) also believes that, if faced with a choice between a globally oriented policy and one that has its primary focus on continuing efforts to harmonize policies with those in the United States, the decision is obvious, given that North America8217s share of the global economy is destined to shrink. In response to this strategic perspective, the tactical approaches to trade policy in the past decade have been thinly spread among multilateral trade negotiations at the World Trade Organization (WTO), non-US bilateral or regional trade negotiations, and Team Canada missions to promote trade and investment across the world. But claims regarding the benefits of such efforts to diversify trade away from the United States are seldom backed by rigorous empirical analysis. This study attempts to fill this void by estimating the economic benefits of implementing a North American customs union and comparing them to the benefits of increasing Canada8217s share of trade with Europe andor large emerging economies. Unlike more traditional analyses of trade diversification, our work examines the potential role of demographic changes on Canada8217s terms of trade and shows that they are large enough to warrant consideration in the development of trade policy. 1 Theoretical Overview of Alternative Trade Policy Directions Before we embark on the empirical analysis, it will be useful to provide the basic theoretical underpinnings of the major strategic options for Canada8217s trade policy and their potential impact on trade diversification. Broadly speaking, there are three options: reduce trade barriers across a wide spectrum of countries (multilateral) deepen the existing North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and reduce trade barriers with a selected group of countries to encourage diversification away from the United States. Trade diversification via multilateral trade negotiations Perhaps the biggest single driver of trade in the post-World War Two period has been the steady drop in tariff rates negotiated through the General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and its successor, the WTO. These multilateral negotiations to reduce trade barriers across a wide spectrum of countries remain, in theory, the best way for Canada (and all other trading nations) to maximize the gains from trade. 2 Furthermore, they remain a good tactic for a country to use to diversify its trading partners, as these negotiations can be viewed as a way to counter the trade-diverting effects created by PTAs, including NAFTA. The pernicious effects of PTAs PTAs, which include regional and bilateral free trade agreements such as NAFTA and customs unions such as the first incarnation of the European Union in the 1960s, seek to reduce or eliminate trade barriers across member countries but to maintain them for nonmembers. The views on these PTAs have evolved throughout the twentieth century. During the 1930s, some nations used foreign trade to try to increase their power, by making other nations more economically dependent on them. Hirschman (1945) gives the following example: Country B may have a comparative advantage in the production of a certain commodity with respect to country A, but not with respect to countries C, D, E, etc. If by some preferential treatment, A induced B to produce this commodity for export, A becomes B8217s only market, and the dependence of B upon A may well be worth to A the economic cost involved in not buying in the cheapest market. (31-2) The establishment of the most favoured nation (MFN) clause in the GATT, and then the WTO, which automatically extends to every member country the lowest tariff extended to any member, was meant to curb the ability of the more powerful market to create political dependence on its trade concessions. As stated by Heidrich and Tussie (2010), in adopting nondiscrimination as a pillar, the GATT system was viewed as a means of eroding trade dependence on imperial powers, while at the same time protecting the interests of smaller nations by curbing the ability of the more powerful countries to threaten suspension of trade preferences. According to Bhagwati (2008), PTAs since World War II have not been motivated by these sordid views of the past, but instead reflect a deep misunderstanding of the critical difference between regional or bilateral trade preferences and genuine nondiscriminatory trade liberalization embodied in the WTO. For Bhagwati, the current tide of PTAs has been the result of politicians mistakenly, and in an uncoordinated fashion, pursuing free trade agreements because they think (erroneously) that they are pursuing a free trade agenda (11). When a PTA is formed and trade barriers are eliminated among members, the result is, of course, freer trade. But if the external barriers are left unchanged by the member countries, then the handicap suffered by nonmembers in the markets of the member countries increases. 3 So PTAs are fundamentally discriminatory, which leads Bhagwati to suggest that in the current pandemic of preferential agreements we should more appropriately call the MFN tariff at the WTO the least favoured nation tariff Bhagwati believes that the cure for the PTA pandemic is to progressively reduce the MFN tariffs to zero, which would effectively eliminate the preferences in PTAs, and therefore make them worthless. Georges (2010) has shown that eliminating MFN tariffs multilaterally would permanently increase Canada8217s real GDP by at least 1 percent (and probably considerably more). All this suggests that Canada should not neglect the importance of multilateral rounds of negotiation at the WTO. Continued multilateral trade liberalization would increase trade between industrialized nations (including Canada) and emerging economies, given that the former generally have much lower MFN tariffs than the latter. Therefore, multilateral tariff reductions would obviate the need for PTAs between Canada and emerging economies to spur diversification. However, given the structural impasse at the Doha Round, this tactic may prove difficult, if not impossible. The problem is the lack of political will and lobbying support. First, Hart (2007, 414) points out that Canada has found itself largely on the sidelines of the WTO negotiations, unable to contribute constructively, in part because Canadian politicians of all stripes, convinced of the political weight of Canada8217s farm lobby,8230insisted that Canada make every effort to bring down trade barriers and subsidies on Canada8217s exports, but not at the expense of supply management and the monopoly marketing of wheat and barley. Second, as Bhagwati (2008, 87) puts it, lobbies provide the foot soldiers in the battles to open trade. To paraphrase him, lobbying money you spend on opening up the Indian market via a bilateral deal will, if successful, get the Indian market opened to you. But if you spend that same money in Geneva, opening up the Indian market on a multilateral basis, the benefits to you will be diluted by free riders from other countries who have not spent any money in support of this goal. Thus, the money is better spent on bilateral agreements. A Canada-US customs union NAFTA eliminated tariffs for continental trade, but each member country retains its individual trade and external tariff policies with respect to nonmember states. This gives an incentive for firms from nonmembers to export their goods to the member country with the lowest external tariffs and then transship to the final destination to take advantage of NAFTA8217s preferential treatment. To avoid such trade deflection, NAFTA (and indeed all FTAs) have rules of origin which are designed to restrict the benefits of the preferential tariff treatment to products manufactured wholly or substantially within the PTA area. This assures that goods that are simply being transshipped or undergoing only minor transformations in a member country will not be deemed as originating in that country and will not receive preferential treatment when reexported to another member country. Whereas an FTA requires preferential rules of origin to prevent trade deflection, a customs union does not. The core elements of a customs union are negotiation of a common external tariff with respect to nonmembers, a revenue-sharing agreement for the customs duties collected at the external border and harmonized external trade policies. Harmonizing external trade barriers with respect to nonmembers eliminates the incentive for trade deflection and transshipment, thus making rules of origin unnecessary: movements of goods within a customs union are not based on their originating status but on the principle of free circulation. 4 Rules of origin are complex and costly to comply with. In NAFTA, there are three tests of origin: the change in tariff classification test (used most frequently), the value content test and the specific production process test. 5 Chapter 4 and annex 401 of NAFTA contain about 200 pages dealing with rules of origin and the interpretation of these rules as they apply to particular products. Many studies have shown that rules of origin, while they eliminate trade deflection, also distort trade flows and reduce efficiencies in the production process. For example, NAFTA rules of origin encourage firms to substitute intermediate goods (that is, parts and components required to produce a finished product) originating in the zone for less expensive non-originating materials in order to obtain preferential trade treatment (see, among others, Krishna 2005 Georges 2008a). This implies that NAFTA rules of origin as currently designed may hinder North American firms from taking full advantage of the global production chains. Eliminating rules of origin would thus serve to encourage geographic diversification of supply chains. A related problem with rules of origin is that fragmentation of supply chains magnifies the complexity of assigning origin to a single country, since many goods use primary factors owned by residents of countries other than that in which the good or stage is produced (a phenomenon associated primarily with foreign direct investment and, to a lesser extent, the international movement of labour). In such a case, the origin of traded goods becomes ambiguous, as it is split between factors owned by residents of a series of countries (Lloyd 1993). A later section of this study will evaluate numerically the effects of, and potential gains from, switching to a customs union with the United States that would also liberalize NAFTA rules of origin. But is the option technically or politically feasible The first important technical challenge with the negotiation of a North American customs union involves harmonizing trade policy. This would not only require selecting a common external tariff or liberalizing NAFTA rules of origin, however. As claimed by Meilke, Rude, and Zahniser (2008), one of the thorniest issues would be the many different FTAs that North American countries have negotiated separately (see figure 3). A full North American customs union could require the eventual reconciliation of the rules of origin used in each FTA (excluding NAFTA, of course, as NAFTA preferential rules of origin would, in theory, no longer exist) in a process similar to the 1997 pan-European diagonal cumulation system implemented by the European Union. Research along the lines of Augier, Gasiorek, and LaiTong (2005) on cumulating rules of origin, and of Cornejo and Harris (2007) on a general origin regime as an indispensable minimum to effectively interconnect existing FTAs, should therefore be pursued and encouraged to better gauge the technical challenge of doing this reconciliation. The second consideration is that moving to a customs union would make rules of origin redundant only if the rules8217 objective was truly to eliminate trade deflection. But that interpretation, however common, is somewhat inconsistent with the observation that the United States is the NAFTA member that insisted on strict rules of origin, whereas it is also the member with the lowest MFN tariffs. Trade deflection would therefore benefit the United States, not Mexico or Canada, in terms of tariff revenues. This suggests that the real reason for having rules of origin in NAFTA (and in any FTA, for that matter) might be rent-seeking activities by interest groups instead of a genuine concern with trade deflection. Indeed, cross-border and intranational coalitions of industries backing duty-free access in exchange for strict rules of origin were probably the leading factor behind the success of FTA negotiations in the 1980s and 1990s (Destler 2006). 6 The logical implication seems to be that these groups will inevitably lobby against rulesof-origin liberalization and, therefore, against any agenda for a North American customs union. This argument against the political feasibility of a customs union may be overstated, however, as the political economy supporting strict rules of origin has been eroding and will continue to erode because of the new international supply chains. For example, according to Baldwin (2009, 40), it may be the case that ROOs rules of origin are saving industry jobs, but whose As unbundling and spatial dispersion of upstream manufacturing proceeds, the nationalistic argument for ROOs tends to get blurred. Moreover, if unbundling results in a multiplication of firms, it will make political organization more difficult. Trade diversification away from the United States via bilateral and preferential trade agreements According to Helliwell (2002, 86), North America is destined, through the joint forces of demography and technological catch-up, to be a smaller and smaller share of the world economy. To focus emphasis on the smaller part of the global pie may seem attractive during booming times in the United States economy, but would be a short-sighted strategy. Although Helliwell8217s thesis is far-reaching and not limited to trade relations, we will illustrate the discourse that this notion typically generates in the context of trade policy. First, trade diversification should not be understood in terms of additional net jobs that Canada8217s trade with non-North American partners might generate. Businessmen and politicians tend to think that an increase in Canadian exports to faster-growing markets will increase employment. However, what might be common sense for particular companies is not necessarily true for a country as a whole (Krugman 1996), in this case because there is an eventual limit to how low the unemployment rate can go without creating unacceptable inflation. If Canada8217s economy were to experience a large surge in exports to, say, China and India, the Bank of Canada would eventually need to offset the expansionary effect of the exports by raising interest rates, and an increase in export-related jobs would be more or less matched by a loss of jobs in interest-rate-sensitive sectors of the economy. Second, trade diversification away from the United States is often construed as an insurance policy for Canada and Canadian exporters against US recessions. In other words, trade diversification would reduce the risk of having all of one8217s eggs in the same basket and therefore reduce the volatility of the incomes of Canadian exporters. Clearly, this view requires that recessions in the rest of the world be unsynchronized with those in the United States if all markets are subject to the same business cycles, then there may be little benefit to diversification in this regard. More fundamentally, welfare gains in standard trade models are derived from specialization in production and trade flows, not from diversification per se. So, the cost of greater income risk must be set against the benefit of specialization. In other words, there might be a trade-off between the gains from specialization derived from deep integration with the United States and the income volatility that the lack of market diversification affords. Goldfarb (2006) has analyzed this portfolio-type argument that the status quo delivers volatility. She argues that over the past decade, Canadian exports to the U. S. have been less volatile on average than have exports to most other regions. Where they have been more volatile, they have been accompanied by significant trade growth. Shifting exports away from the U. S. over the past decade would have increased volatility and decreased trade growth, making Canada worse off, assuming all else was equal (18). In the same vein, Beaulieu and Emery (2006, 269) argue that incomes from trade can be expected to be high and low depending on demand for Canada8217s exports, but total income over time will presumably be maximized by Canada specializing in its comparative advantage and exporting to the highest price buyer8230This will mean that we remain highly dependent on the U. S. market and subject to considerable income risk and income volatility. For them, income-smoothing tools (employment insurance, personal savings) and institutions (the Canadian Wheat Board and other price and revenue stabilization funds) are the proper instruments for addressing these issues of volatility in economic markets as a more direct alternative to a strategy of diversifying export markets. Export diversification is often dismissed from another angle by questioning the ability of governments to change trade patterns. For example, Goldfarb (2006, 2) claims that individuals, rather than governments, determine economy-wide trade patterns, which would in part explain why past efforts by governments to change trade patterns have failed. Taken at face value, this argument seems, in a slightly cavalier way, to dispose of 60 years of research on trade creation and diversion effects due to (government-negotiated) FTAs, and possibly to underestimate the current Canadian concerns with respect to (government-imposed) border security measures post-911. However, as Goldfarb rightly points out, for now, businesses continue to solidify their economic links in the U. S. while growing them at a faster rate outside of the U. S. as opportunities arise and relative risks fall (26). And indeed, businesses take advantage of these opportunities. For example, Cadot et al. (2010) have shown that since the early 2000s OECD markets have been diversifying their sources of supplies geographically, and that this recent trend of import diversification is broadly consistent with a quality search model where buyers screen foreign suppliers (and hence countries) for quality before deciding which suppliers should be included in cross-country supply chains. As noted earlier, figure 1 also shows a clear trend toward increased import diversification for Canada since 1998. This might suggest that import rather than export diversification, is a relevant, even if neglected, issue, and that the Canadian government should bend with the wind of marketdriven import diversification. 7 Consistent with Beaulieu and Emery (2006), the natural policy approach seems to let Canada specialize in its comparative advantage while freely importing from the lowest costprice producers. This, of course, is also consistent with our viewpoint that further multilateral negotiations at the WTO remain important, as does further liberalization of (NAFTA) rules of origin, with the aim of giving Canadian firms full advantage of global supply chains. This also is consistent with a government-led intensification of trade flows to and from emerging markets, implemented through selected FTAs, which would enable Canada to import more intensively from low-cost sources as well as providing larger export markets. Potential Benefits of a North American Customs Union As noted previously, all FTAs have rules of origin designed to restrict the benefits of the preferential tariff treatment to products originating in the member countries. Being the gatekeepers of preferential trade, rules of origin also eliminate trade deflection by ensuring that goods that are simply being transshipped through a member country or undergoing only minor transformations there will not be deemed to originate in that country, and will not receive preferential treatment when re-exported to another member country. However, rules of origin are also costly, and to gauge these costs, the econometric literature has constructed an index of the restrictiveness of rules of origin as an independent variable in order to estimate their economic impact on bilateral trade flows, preferential tariff utilization rates and investment flows. 8 On the basis of these studies, it is now generally acknowledged that in some instances firms have decided to pay the MFN tariff rather than to incur the cost of complying with rules of origin, automatically cancelling the potential trade-creating benefits of FTAs. Also, the diversity of rules of origin across FTAs has severely limited interregional trade flows, and the restrictiveness of some rules of origin is beyond the levels that would be justified to prevent trade deflection. 9 Whereas an FTA requires preferential rules of origin to prevent trade deflection, a customs union does not. Hence, some economists have suggested transforming NAFTA into a customs union (e. g. Kunimoto and Sawchuk 2005 Ghosh and Rao 2005 Pastor 2008 Georges 2008b, 2010). Gauging the economic impact of converting NAFTA into a customs union requires estimating the joint effect of adopting a common external tariff and eliminating rules of origin, which can (roughly) be decomposed into two effects: (1) the pure effect derived from the adoption of a common external tariff, and (2) the pure effect derived from the elimination of rules of origin. Given that the two joint policies imply complex interconnections between the use of raw materials, intermediate goods and value added, Georges (2008b) proposes a general equilibrium framework to gauge the impact of moving from NAFTA to a customs union that also eliminates rules of origin. The approach uses a multicountry, multisector, dynamic general equilibrium model in which the world economy consists of seven countriesregions divided into two groups: NAFTA countries (Canada, the United States and Mexico) and non-NAFTA countries (Mercosur which consists of Brazil, Argentina, Paraguay and Uruguay the rest of Latin America Europe and the rest of the world). Each country has eight sectors of production: agriculture, natural resources, food processing, textiles and clothing, manufacturing, technology products, automotive products, and services). We set the common external tariff to the existing US external tariff (currently the lowest, on average, of the three NAFTA members), on the assumption of limited Canadian negotiation power on this score. 10 With regard to the costs of rules of origin, the modelling approach is based on the fact that they act as an implicit tax to NAFTA firms for the use of non-originating intermediate goods, but as an implicit subsidy for the use of capital, labour and intermediate goods purchased within NAFTA (see Georges 2008a for a mathematical approach to this problem and Georges 2010 for a graphical presentation). Therefore, the main impact of removing rules of origin is to reallocate efficiently the demand for factors of production in each sector of the NAFTA countries, lowering NAFTA firms8217 demand for capital, labour and NAFTA intermediate goods, but increasing the demand for non-NAFTA intermediate goods. The efficient reallocation of factors of production within NAFTA will also lower the unit cost of production in every sector of the NAFTA countries. 11 Using this modelling approach, we compare two counterfactual scenarios: (1) negotiation of a North American customs union in the mid-1990s (replacing NAFTA) (2) negotiation of such a customs union in the early 2000s. Figure 4 shows the results of the simulations and decomposes the sources of the gains into those due to the common external tariff, those due to eliminating rules of origin, and those due to a cross effect of both factors. 12 The first observation is that the benefits of a customs union tend to decrease over time. The benefits would have been much larger had a customs union been negotiated as part of replacing or upgrading NAFTA in the mid-1990s. This would have led to a permanent increase of nearly 1 percent of Canadian GDP (about 15 billion per year in today8217s dollars). If we had waited a decade to negotiate such an agreement, the benefits would have been only about half as large. The likely reason why potential benefits have declined since the 1990s is that multi-lateral tariff reductions agreed to in 1994 during the Uruguay Round (which were gradually implemented over the following decade) have reduced the relative advantage of NAFTA (i. e. MFN) tariff preferences. As a result, it became more common for North American firms to pay non-NAFTA tariffs for intracontinental exports rather than bearing the costs of complying with rules of origin. This pattern provides empirical confirmation of the notion that PTAs lose their value with declines in MFN tariffs agreed during multilateral rounds (Bhagwati 2008), as discussed earlier. The second important point is that elimination of rules of origin matters to Canada more than a common external tariff. Figure 4 shows that elimination of rules of origin accounts for the vast bulk of economic benefits. Therefore, the main motivation for advocating a North American customs union should be rules-oforigin liberalization and not the establishment of a common external tariff. In terms of effects on specific sectors, negotiating a customs union would have had the strongest impacts on the natural resources, automotive products and technology products sectors (figure 5). Recalling that the removal of NAFTA rules of origin eliminates the implicit subsidy on North American intermediate goods and lowers the costs of final goods, then, sectors of production should be negatively affected by this shock when their production is used as intermediate goods, and positively affected when their production is for final uses. All sectors of the economy use natural resources intensively as an intermediate good. Therefore, the removal of rules of origin induces strong substitution of nonNAFTA resources, which has a negative impact on the Canadian resources sector (-6.6 percent in figure 5). The automobile and technology products sectors intensively use intermediate goods, and they gain from rules-of-origin liberalization (13.4 percent and 3.3 percent), as they are in position to buy cheaper intermediate goods from the rest of the world, which improves their efficiency (see Georges 2010 for further details). 13 In conclusion, the idea that a North American customs union and elimination of rules of origin hold large aggregate economic benefits for Canada is not borne out by quantitative analysis. The economic effects are positive, but they have decreased over time, and will continue to decrease to the extent that multilateral tariffs continue to fall. We estimate that negotiating a customs union with the United States and Mexico would increase Canadian output by about 0.5 percent annually, or 7 billion in today8217s dollars. Potential Benefits of Diversifying Trade Away from the United States: The Demographic Dimension As noted earlier, arguments in favour of diversifying trade away from the United States to other parts of the world are not new. Some of them, such as the notion that diversification would reduce the volatility of Canada8217s trade flows, are not supported by recent data on economic volatility (Goldfarb 2006). Others, such as the notion that Canada should seek to spur trade ties to fast-growing emerging markets, are actually being borne out to varying degrees as a result of market forces. For example, Canadian exports to countries outside the OECD increased from 8 percent in 2004 to 15 percent in 2009, while the US share decreased from 84 percent to 74 percent. Here we examine a demographic argument in favour of trade diversification. The link between demographic change and trade patterns A typical framework (see, for example, Foot 2007) used to discuss the impact of population aging on GDP per capita decomposes this ratio into five terms productivity, effort, employment rate, labour force participation and the ratio of adults to total population: The literature generally suggests that population aging might tend to reduce the first four ratios to the extent that older workers are less productive, they choose to work fewer hours, they are discriminated against owing to their age, or they decide to retire early and leave the labour force entirely. It is thus generally thought that aging societies are at risk of economic slowdown relative to more youthful nations. Trade fits into this framework indirectly at best, to the extent that international trade tends to enhance productivity (see Lopez 2005 for a survey of the trade-productivity literature). However, the impact of trade flows can be more clearly understood if we look at how the terms of trade affect the relationship between real gross domestic income and real gross domestic product. In a closed economy (with no tax), these quantities are identical, because the price index for produced goods is the same as the price index for purchased goods. But in the presence of international trade, the price indices for produced and consumed goods need not be the same, and variations in the ratio (known as the terms of trade) can have a strong impact on consumption (and therefore economic well-being), as illustrated in the following equation: where real consumption (per capita) is defined as real disposable income minus real private saving, and the term of trade is given by the ratio of PQ (the price of the domestically produced goods) over PCON (the consumer price index defined as a weighted average of the price of the domestically produced goods and the foreign produced goods). An example is Canada8217s experience in the 2000s. Thanks to a commodities boom that increased the prices paid for Canada8217s raw materials exports (combined with relatively stable consumer prices), Canada8217s terms of trade improved dramatically. From 2003 to 2008, Canada8217s real gross domestic product grew by 2.5 percent annually, but real gross domestic income increased by 3.9 percent annually. The extra purchasing power was due to improvements in the terms of trade. While the impact of demographic change on GDP per capita is well understood, it is also true that global demographic shifts can have marked effects on the terms of trade. As a nation8217s population ages, the supply of the goods it produces falls while their prices increase, hence improving its terms of trade relative to younger nations. Clearly, a relatively closed economy could not benefit from improvement in terms of trade. But an open economy with some market power, such as Canada, could potentially mitigate the adverse economic impact of an aging domestic population by selecting younger (and faster-growing) trade partners. This would result in stronger downward pressures on Canada8217s consumer price index (as consumers and firms import more from countries with relatively falling producer prices owing to their young population and fast growth), thus improving further its terms of trade. (Note that some degree of specialization and thus market power in production is essential for the terms of trade effects we describe here. 14 ) To examine this demographic dimension of trade diversification, we draw on work by Georges, Merette, and Seckin (2009), which uses a multicountry overlapping-generations model that is fully described in Merette and Georges (2010). The model economy is made up of seven regions. North America is disaggregated into the United States and Canada, to distinguish the impacts of aging on a relatively closed economy from those on an open economy. Europe is aggregated into one region: the EU-15. 15 Asia is disaggregated into three countries: Japan, a developed country with an already aging population and China and India, emerging countries with very different demographic projections. The rest of the world is aggregated into one residual region. International trade is modelled by assuming that each region in the model produces a single good that is an imperfect substitute for the good produced in any other region. Therefore, households in each region consume a basket of all the goods produced in all regions of the world. Demographic projections and simulation results Population aging results from a combination of factors, the most important of which are rising life expectancy and declining fertility rates. Table 1 provides the assumptions behind the medium variant scenario of the United Nations demographic projections in each region of the world, including the effects of international migration. The demographic assumptions contained in table 1 can be used to project the impact on the old age dependency ratio (population aged 65 and over as a ratio of the population aged 15 to 64) as given in figure 6, for each region of the world, over the period 2000-60. As can be seen, Japan is by far the fastest aging country, with the elderly dependency ratio rising from 28 percent in 2000 to 70 percent by 2040. The EU-15 has the second-highest ratio, followed by Canada, whose elderly dependency ratio is expected to rise from 18 percent in 2000 to about 43 percent in 2040. In contrast, the United States has a more moderate increase in the elderly dependency ratio, which is projected to move from 19 percent in 2000 to 32 percent in 2040, in part because it has a much higher total fertility rate than most industrialized countries. The Chinese elderly dependency ratio follows a quite different pattern than that in the other regions. In 2000, China had one of the lowest ratios (about 10 percent). However, the drastic fall in the fertility rate starting in the 1979 as a result of the one-child policy, combined with net out-migration will lead to a sharp increase in the dependency ratio over the next several decades, reaching 30 percent in 2040 and continuing to rise. Finally, India has a relatively young population, and its elderly dependency ratio is expected to rise only modestly from 10 percent in 2000 to less than 20 percent in 2040. As noted earlier, population aging will lead to a reduction in labour force growth, which will put downward pressure on GDP growth. Figure 7 illustrates the impact of population aging in our multicountry model on real GDP per capita through 2060, abstracting from technical progress (that is, total factor productivity growth). For ease of comparison across regions, variables are normalized to 100 in 2000. As expected, among all regions, Japan and the EU-15 are the most negatively affected by population aging, with an earlier and sharper decline than the others in real GDP per capita. Aging has already begun to exert a negative effect on real GDP per capita in both Japan and the EU-15, although this effect has been delayed somewhat in other regions. Population aging in Japan and the EU-15 is projected to reduce real GDP per capita by about 15 percent between 2000 and 2050. Soon, North America will also be negatively affected by aging. Demographically driven real GDP per capita for Canada and the United States peaks in 2010, but population aging will lead to declines thereafter. The impact of aging on Canada is much more pronounced, with a fall of 11 percent between 2000 and 2050 as opposed to 6 percent for the United States over the same period. Looking at the other side of the aging spectrum, India has a relatively young population and strongly benefits from the demographic changes as its real GDP per capita increases until 2030 and then stabilizes thereafter at that level. Finally, the impact of aging in China is stunning. The Chinese economy has an abundant workforce at the turn of the twenty-first century, and this has supported real GDP per capita until now. Soon, however, as the demographic shock in China resulting from the one-child policy starts to kick in, the labour supply falls dramatically and contributes to lower real GDP per capita. By 2050, the fall in real GDP per capita (of close to 15 percent with respect to 2000) is similar to the one Japan is likely to experience. It is important to recall that technical progress and innovation, which contribute to long-term growth in GDP, have been excluded from these forecasts, and in that sense the figures reaffirm the need for aging societies to adopt policies to accelerate productivity growth. In Canada, for instance, these projections imply that total factor productivity growth must increase by at least 13 percent over the next 40 years just to prevent GDP per capita from declining, let alone continuing to grow at rates to which Canadians are accustomed. Although the demographically driven downward pressure on GDP per capita will contribute to lower consumption per capita, globalization through international trade can help offset some of this through favourable terms of trade effects. To the extent that population aging reduces the relative supply of a country8217s good with respect to that in other regions, the relative price of its good will increase, and older countries should see an improvement in their terms of trade. Table 2 illustrates this by showing the projected terms of trade for the seven regions included in our model, and confirms that the fastest-aging nations have the largest increases in their terms of trade. An improvement in the terms of trade means that countries can import more than before for a given amount of exports, thus allowing domestic real consumption to increase. Figure 8 shows projected changes in per capita real consumption driven by demographic change (and the resultant changes in terms of trade) for the seven regions, and the patterns are quite different from those for per capita GDP. Real consumption per capita in Japan tends to fall because of the strong fall in GDP per capita shown in figure 7. Although Japan does see strong aging-related improvement in its terms of trade, the economic benefits are negligible because international trade is a relatively small share of its economy. In contrast, the more open economies of Canada and the EU-15 strongly benefit from the terms of trade appreciation. Indeed, for Canada this effect offsets the negative effect of aging on GDP per capita shown in figure 7, allowing real consumption per capita to increase until 2020, after which it declines until 2050 by roughly 3 percent. While the United States outperforms Canada in terms of demographically driven GDP per capita, Canada8217s per capita consumption does not fall below its 2010 level for most of the twenty-first century, whereas the United States remains below its 2010 level for most of the following decades. This reflects the fact that Canada has a more open economy and its terms of trade are likely to improve more. Because Canada8217s consumption per capita will move in the opposite direction to GDP per capita until 2020, the Canadian economy will experience an enriching decay, that is, the improvement in the terms of trade is large enough to outweigh the negative impact of aging on domestic economic growth. This situation is the opposite of the famous immiserizing growth scenario described by Bhagwati (1958). India gets a strong boost in real consumption per capita, despite deterioration in its terms of trade, as a result of a strong positive GDP per capita effect. This effect is itself stimulated by capital deepening in India, as its advantageous demographic position increases the productivity of capital and attracts foreign investment (Merette and Georges 2010). The case of China is again striking, especially when observing the diametrically opposite directions taken by China and India8217s real consumption paths from 2000 on. For China, both GDP and terms of trade effects contribute to reinforce the negative impact on real consumption per capita. Indeed, the timing of the one-child policy makes the Chinese economy a (still) relatively young country with respect to OECD countries but also an old one with respect to India and other parts of the world. Being caught between younger and older countries, the Chinese economy does not benefit from terms of trade appreciation occurring in the older, more open OECD countries, nor does it strongly benefit from capital deepening through net foreign capital inflows (Merette and Georges 2010). Economic effects of trade diversification away from the United States The foregoing projections have assumed that Canada pursues no explicit policies to diversify trade away from the United States. However, by examining alternative scenarios in which trade shares are modified from their baseline values, we can estimate the effect of trade diversification away from the United States on Canada8217s real consumption per capita. Figure 9 shows how Canada would gain or lose in terms of real consumption per capita if it diversified its trade away from the United States in favour of specific trade partners. For these experiments, we reduced the US share in total Canadian imports by 10 percentage points, a 2.5 percentage point increment every decade for 40 years, while successively increasing the share of other partners (see table 3 for details on alternative scenarios). Our results indicate that, relative to the baseline case of unchanged US trade dependence, Canadians would benefit from a diversification scheme with India the improvement in terms of trade would be large enough to boost Canadian consumption per capita by almost 4 percent relative to 2010 and to a lower degree with China. In sharp contrast, a diversification scheme with the EU-15 or with Japan would actually reduce real consumption per capita slightly. For example, if Canadian firms and consumers increased the share of Indian goods in their imports by 10 percentage points, this would offset the negative impact of aging by propping up the real consumption per capita along a slowly upward-sloping path above its 2020 level. Therefore, between 2020 and 2050, real consumption per capita in Canada would increase by about 1.9 percent instead of falling by 2.8 percent, and would stand at roughly 4.7 percent above its baseline level in 2050. Diversifying to the EU-15 instead of India would cost Canadians roughly 6 percent of real consumption per capita by 2050. Figure 10 shows the results for diversification schemes to mature industrialized economies and emerging economies. In the mature markets, the shares of Japanese and EU-15 goods each increase by 5 percentage points in total Canadian imports, while the US share falls by 10 percentage points. The emerging markets diversification scheme represents a weighted average of the previous diversification schemes to China, India and the rest of the world the 10 percentage point share increase is spread equally between the three regions. The rest of the world is a composite of all remaining countriesregions of the world, such as Russia, Africa, Brazil and South America, Oceania, the Arab countries, Turkey and the Central Asian countries. Figure 10 illustrates that, according to our simulations, emerging-market diversification schemes may prop up Canadian real consumption per capita, whereas mature-market diversification schemes would amplify the expected burden associated with population aging in Canada. The broad strategic choice of diversifying to mature markets instead of emerging markets would cost Canadians roughly 5 percent of real consumption per capita by 2050. Caveats regarding our models We need to be very explicit about what our modelling exercise does and does not do. Our focus has been on the impact on real consumption of an exogenous change in trade shares that would diversify our trade pattern away from the United States, and not on the mechanism that might lead to a change in these shares. The size, composition and direction of trade flows result from the decisions of millions of private producers and consumers. Government policy may have an influence on these decisions, but bringing about a large and rapid shift of trade shares might require strong policy measures. 16 When Prime Minister Diefenbaker announced in 1957 that Canada would switch 15 percent of its trade from the United States to Great Britain, his plan would have required a doubling of UK exports to Canada, a willingness by Canadians to shun the many desirable goods they were buying from the United States while substituting less desirable goods from the United Kingdom, and the capacity of UK customers to double the value of their Canadian purchases (Hart 2002). Diefenbaker8217s policy was blurred by nostalgia for Canada8217s historic ties to Britain and by a lack of appreciation of commercial realities. Bearing his example in mind, we stress the importance of supplementing our analysis with studies of policies and institutions, such as bilateral trade agreements, that might be used to bring about endogenous changes in trade shares. A related but more subtle caveat asks whether we should even consider changing the baseline shares of the model. These trade shares are presumably already optimally chosen on the basis of the exogenous variables and parameters in the model. If we change the shares, we change consumer preferences so that we cannot make meaningful comparisons. 17 But are these baseline shares truly optimal Existing trade shares reflect all sorts of distortions in the economy, and the presence of social capital (trust, networks) or its lack may still prevent Canada from establishing deep economic ties with India, China or Brazil, even if these ties are desirable. Another caveat is the reliance of our model on a trade structure that assumes some degree of imperfect substitution between goods of different geographical origins, so that the law of one price does not hold. This assumption has been crucial in the economic literature (Helpman and Krugman 1985) in explaining some robust features of international trade, such as substantial two-way trade in similar products (intrasectoral trade) between countries. However, it also implies that each country has market power (and thus faces a downward-sloping export demand curve), so that quantity adjustment by producers to diverse shocks is somewhat muted by the lack of direct competition between regional producers, while terms of trade effects are greater as larger price changes are necessary to clear markets. 18 This assumption could be relaxed in future multisectoral analyses, depending on the nature of the goods (i. e. differentiated manufactured goods versus homogeneous primary goods that would follow the law of one price). Policy Implications We believe that the bilateral and regional trade agreements, which have proliferated in recent years a phenomenon referred to as the spaghetti bowl of PTAs are termites in the trading system that undermines true multilateral free trade (Bhagwati 2008). These agreements have become a way for the United States and the European Union to impose all sorts of trade-unrelated issues, cynically called trade-related issues in treaties. These include intellectual property protection, domestic environmental issues and labour standards, the last two presented as if they were altruistic measures aimed at benefiting foreign workers, even when they mask self-interest and new forms of protectionism. Multilateral trade liberalization negotiations at the WTO, which avoid quests for preferential access, remain the best strategy for countries seeking to take advantage of the international specialization of labour. 19 They permit countries to diversify trade partners by eliminating or mitigating trade preferences and their distortions. In consequence, the WTO model should be embraced by those in Canada who advocate trade diversification away from the United States. Given the political impasse at the WTO, Canadian policy-makers would be wise to consider second-best strategic options. This study has examined two possibilities: enhancing and deepening continental trade by negotiating a North American customs union, and attempting to diversify trade away from the United States to other regions of the world. The main benefit of a continental customs union would be the elimination of NAFTA rules of origin, which would reduce compliance costs and eliminate implicit subsidies and taxes on North American and foreign raw materials, intermediate goods and value added. Canadian firms could thus purchase intermediate goods where they are the cheapest, lowering production costs and enhancing competitiveness, which would induce further exports elsewhere in the world. Hence, paradoxically, deepening continental integration via a Canada-US customs union is another strategic direction, one that could also contribute to diversification of trade away from North America. If Canada is in search of a policy measure that might reconcile opponents and proponents of increased regionalism, this might be the one. Trade resources could be allocated away from the failed acronymic initiatives of the 1990s and 2000s (shown in figure 1) in order to pursue this option. However, our quantitative analysis shows that the long-term economic benefits are small about 0.5 percent of GDP annually (7 billion in current dollars) and will continue to get smaller to the extent that MFN tariffs continue to fall. With regard to the second strategic option, the economic benefits of diversifying trade away from the United States appear potentially larger than those of deepening North American integration, so long as trading partners are selected carefully. To date, however, Canada has adopted a scattershot approach, as shown in the box. As a general rule, Canada should negotiate agreements with relatively youthful nations (such as India, Brazil and, to a lesser extent, China) to take advantage of demographically driven improvements in its terms of trade as well as strong economic growth in these nations. Trade diversification to India, for example, would increase Canadian real per capita consumption by 2050 by nearly 5 percent relative to the scenario with no diversification. A more general effort to diversify trade to emerging markets outside North America and the EU-15 would result in a 3 percent increase in per capita consumption. From a demographic perspective, it would be unwise for Canada to try to diversify trade to Japan and Europe, notwithstanding the current government8217s intention to move ahead with negotiations for a comprehensive economic and trade agreement with the European Union. Our simulations show that this would actually reduce real consumption per capita relative to the scenario with no diversification. Canadian trade policy-makers might well reconsider the wisdom of pursuing these talks at the expense of other trade negotiations. Although the growth potential of China has attracted much attention, an analysis that takes into account demographic factors shows that India is an even more promising market in the twenty-first century. It may achieve its potential if it pursues its efforts to integrate the world economy through liberalization of both trade and capital flows, while accelerating the movement of its workforce out of agriculture and into the unskilled-labour-intensive industry of the organized sector (Panagariya 2006). Factors other than demographics clearly go into making a country an attractive trading partner for Canada. The most important of these are innovation and productivity, which serve not only to spur faster economic growth in our potential export markets, but also allow the fruits of foreign innovation to spill over to Canadian firms via foreign direct investment. Indeed, one of the great advantages of having such close trade ties to the United States is privileged access to the many innovations that originate there. While forecasts of global innovation are beyond the scope of this study, it is clear that China and India are both striving to transform their economies into innovation leaders, and their efforts only strengthen the argument for developing deeper Canadian trade ties with them. Their transformation into innovation leaders would also reinforce the favourable terms of trade effects. The tough question is, of course, how to diversify trade. As noted earlier, trade patterns are the result of millions of individual decisions made in the context of an existing set of tariffs and preferences. Past efforts to significantly change Canada8217s trade patterns largely failed to meet their goals. Policy-makers must see this diversification strategy as a long-term proposition by which cultural and nonbusiness ties, trust and networks can pave the way for trade missions and an eventual preferential trade agreement with countries such as India, Brazil and China. India is a promising candidate, because in addition to India8217s advantageous demographics and other circumstances, Canada8217s large Indian diaspora has already helped build cultural ties between the two nations, which also share a history as former possessions of Great Britain. As Dobson (2006, 20) suggests, India8217s demography and economic momentum argue for greater Canadian policy attention she argues that an FTA negotiation would send a powerful signal of commitment8230to Canadian businesses interested in penetrating the Indian market and using India as a platform for Asian operations. The key point here is that the positive influence of export lobbying would offset the negative lobbying of the import-competing interests and could thus accelerate negotiations. The United States is India8217s obvious strategic priority in the Western hemisphere, but a recent analysis of the feasibility of a comprehensive USIndia bilateral FTA concluded that neither country was ready for such an agreement (Bery, Bosworth, and Panagariya 2005). The recent announcement of trade negotiations between Canada and India is a significant strategic signal of India8217s potential importance to the North American economies and will serve Indian interests beyond the Canadian market. By engaging in the three-quarters of the economy outside the US, as Head (2007) puts it, Canada has the opportunity to broaden the trade-driven growth that is essential to its economic well-being while continuing to reap the benefits of its geographic and economic proximity to the United States. In the same spirit, Acemoglu and Ventura (2002) emphasize the role of terms of trade for world income distribution. Since Adam Smith, the argument in favour of free trade has lain in specialization and the international division of labour. The case for free trade has often been questioned by non-economists, but also by great economists such as John Stuart Mill, John Maynard Keynes, Gottfried Haberler, Paul Krugman, and Jagdish Bhagwati. However, as clearly established by Bhagwati and Ramaswami (1963), these criticisms are based on the presence of economic distortions. In the context of a small open economy, the case for free trade is restored once an appropriate policy is adopted to neutralize the existing domestic distortion. This, of course, contrasts the trade creation versus trade diversion effects underlined by Viner (1950). Since Viner, the development of the literature can be seen as an attempt to identify particular circumstances in which the formation of PTAs will provide net economic benefits that is, when the effects of trade creation more than offset those of trade diversion. The European Union, for example, does not impose preferential rules of origin among its members, as it is a customs union. Of course, it does have rules-of-origin regimes with countries external to the union and which have signed FTAs with it. According to the change in tariff classification test, goods produced in one or more of the three countries with nonoriginating materials may be freely traded (i. e. exempted from tariff) when, after the manufacturing process, all such materials (excepting a de minimis amount) undergo a change in tariff classification based upon the Harmonized Tariff System. According to the value content test, some goods must also contain a minimum regional value content defined as the transaction value of a good minus the value of non-originating materials which, when expressed as a percentage, must be at least 60 percent in order to free trade the goods under NAFTA. Alternatively, there is also a net cost value method, because manipulation of prices in transfers among corporate affiliates might otherwise take advantage of NAFTA8217s transaction value method. In this case, the relevant percentage is 50 percent. Finally, the specific production process criterion specifies that for some goods there might be a particular production process that must be employed. Coalitions can be international or intranational coalitions, and are typically between intermediate-good sectors and final-good producers. For example, Mexican tomato paste producers may lobby for tomato ketchup to be included in the Mexican list of duty-free goods if this gives a tariff preference to US ketchup producers that is sufficiently large to induce them to fulfill the rules of origin by switching from cheaper Chilean to Mexican tomato paste. The gain for Mexicans is a new export market for their tomato paste, while the US ketchup producers can export duty free to Mexico. Mexican ketchup producers who have traditionally used (protected) Mexican tomato paste (and therefore who are already satisfying rules of origin) might tolerate the inclusion of ketchup in the Mexican duty-free list even if they are likely to lose from tariff removal, because a strict rules-of-origin regime will raise the costs of their US rivals more than their own. The emphasis on import trade shares instead of export shares or export diversification might be more relevant to the case of trade diversification, at least in a long-term perspective. According to classical trade theory, higher exports are not an end in themselves (at the macro level of the economy, not necessarily at the micro level of the individual firm), and the main objective of international trade is (and the ensuing gains from trade for a country as a whole come from) the possibility of importing some goods at a relatively lower price than the opportunity cost of producing them with domestic resources. This view has been best described by Krugman (1993), where he says that the need to export is a burden that a country must bear because its import suppliers are crass enough to demand payments. Of course, this view is debatable, especially in the short run. In a situation of economic slack and recessions, one can consider exports as an incentive to employment and national income, and imports as leakages that, to a certain degree, prevent the working of this incentive. In this case, the real benefit arising from trade lies in exports rather than imports, and the danger of losing a market if political or economic conditions deteriorate makes for as much concern as the danger of losing supplies. See, for example, Estevadeordal (2000) Estevadeordal and Suominen (2008) Cadot, Estevadeordal, and SuwaEisenmann (2006) Carrre and de Melo (2004) Kunimoto and Sawchuk (2005) and Esteavadeordal, Lopez-Cordova, and Suominen (2008). These econometric studies are not without problems, however, because the use of preferential access in an FTA (and the concomitant rules-of-origin compliance) is an option, not an obligation, so that Estevadeordal8217s index of ex ante rules-of-origin restrictiveness is less relevant than the ex post restrictiveness, or efficiency cost, of these rules. See Georges (2010) for a review of some proposals on simplification or harmonization of rules-of-origin between sectors or across FTAs, and see Lloyd (1993, 2002) for an interesting proposal for a rule-of-origin criterion based on multiple (instead of single) originating countries (as several countries typically contribute to the value added of the traded goods). It seems reasonable enough to suggest an across-the-board standard instead of the current heterogeneous rules across sectors (e. g. the NAFTA triple transformation test in the textileapparel sectors and the 62.5 percent test in the automobile sector). In practice, however, as argued by Destler (2006), harmonization across sectors would be difficult to achieve on a large scale simply because these rules resulted from hardly disputed sector-specific negotiations and their current settings matter a great deal to producers. Rules of origin should not be viewed as a deal between nations but instead as a deal between private business interests and governments that needed to obtain businesses8217 support in the legislative battle. Even a common external tariff set equal to the US MFN is likely to generate much lobbying, negotiation and opposition. Industries where Canadian or Mexican MFN tariffs have to be reduced to US levels are likely to oppose such a move. Furthermore, foreigners are likely to oppose the (less common) cases of upward adjustment of Canadian or Mexican external tariffs to US levels, which would violate article 24 of the WTO (in cases where actual external tariffs are at their WTO bound levels) and trigger retaliation or require compensation. Note that moving from NAFTA to a customs union is not necessarily welfare-improving according to the general principle known as the theory of the second best, which states that, in a system with several distortions, the removal of any one of them cannot be presumed to be welfare-improving. Indeed, Georges (2008a) shows that NAFTA countries might potentially suffer from a deterioration in its terms of trade because the additional demand for non-NAFTA intermediate goods will increase the international price of these goods. This suggests an analogy with the theory of optimal tariff and reflects the fact that North American firms, taken together, constitute a significant share of the world demand for intermediate goods, and hence have the potential to affect world prices. Thus, the net effect of the removal of NAFTA rules of origin on welfare is ambiguous in theory and requires empirical analysis to verify. The full impact of adopting a customs union also includes cross effects. The removal of NAFTA rules of origin per se modifies trade patterns between NAFTA and non-NAFTA countries. Therefore, second-order effects measure the impact that the adoption of a common external tariff might also have on the new pattern of trade when rules of origin are removed, with repercussions on all variables in the model. As these cross effects are relatively small, we will not discuss them further. The sectoral results must be interpreted with extreme caution. Most rules of origin are legislated at highly disaggregated levels and differ across industries within the eight broad sectors in our model, which makes interpreting these aggregate results difficult. This warrants further, more detailed, sectoral analyses. This assumption has proved to be crucial in explaining robust features of international trade, such as the substantial two-way trade in products of similar factor intensities. Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. It is clear that that there is and will always be an asymmetry in a regional agreement between Canada and the United States. Transposing Hirschman8217s case study (1945) of Germany and Bulgaria to the United States and Canada, we see that trade with Canada represents roughly 16 percent of total US trade for both imports and exports, while trade with the United States represents about 61 percent and 75 percent of Canada8217s total imports and exports, respectively. It would be much more difficult for Canada to shift trade with the United States to other countries than it would be for the United States to replace Canada as a market and a source of supplies. As one of this paper8217s referees nicely put it, If people could be made to like water better than wine, then welfare would go up, since water is cheaper to produce than wine. But if the utility function can be changed at will, then any level of welfare is attainable. Note, however, that we report preand post-real aggregate consumption levels, not strictly a welfare level (which, in an overlapping generations model, is cohort-based). See Lloyd and Zhang (2006) and Zhang (2006) for papers on the effects of this assumption, here modelled using the Armington (1969) trade framework. Furthermore, despite the precedent set by the agreement on intellectual property rights, Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) at the WTO, demanded by the United States, weaker countries could better resist the pressures of the United States and the European Union by the sheer force of numbers. Acemoglu, D. and J. Ventura. 2002. The World Income Distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 659-94. Armington, P. S. 1969. A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production. IMF Staff Papers 16: 159-76. Augier, P. M. Gasiorek, and C. Lai-Tong. 2005. The Impact of Rules of Origin on Trade Flows. Economic Policy 20 (43): 567-624. Baldwin, R. 2009. Integration of the North American Economy and New-Paradigm Globalization. Working paper 049, Policy Research Initiative, Government of Canada. Beaulieu, E. and H. Emery. 2006. Stay the Course or Find a New Path Canada8217s Reliance on the U. S. as an Export Market. In Nafta 10, edited by J. Curtis and A. Sydor. Ottawa: Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada. Bery, S. B. Bosworth, and A. Panagariya. 2005. The India Policy Forum 2004. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Bhagwati, J. 1958. Immiserizing Growth: A Geometrical Note. Review of Economic Studies 25 (3): 201-5. 821282128212821282128212. 2008. Termites in the Trading Systems How Preferential Agreements Undermine Free Trade. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bhagwati, J. and V. K. Ramaswami. 1963. Domestic Distortions, Tariffs, and the Theory of Optimum Subsidy. Journal of Political Economy 71 (1): 44-50. Cadot, O. C. Carrre, M. Kukenova, and V. Stauss-Kahn. 2010. OECD Imports: Diversification and Quality Search. Policy Research working paper WPS 5285, World Bank. Cadot, O. A. Estevadeordal, and A. Suwa-Eisenmann. 2006. Rules of Origin as Export Subsidies. In The Origin of Goods: Rules of Origin in Regional Trade Agreements, edited by O. Cadot, A. Estevadeordal, A. Suwa-Eisenmann, and T. Verdier. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Carrre, C. and J. de Melo. 2004. Are Differential Rules of Origin Equally Costly Estimates from NAFTA. Discussion paper series no. 4437, CEPR. Cornejo, R. and J. Harris. 2007. Convergence in the Rules of Origin Spaghetti Bowl: A Methodological Proposal. Working paper no. 34, INTAL-INT, Inter-American Development Bank. Destler, I. M. 2006. Rules of Origin and US Trade Policy. In The Origin of Goods: Rules of Origin in Regional Trade Agreements, edited by O. Cadot, A. Estevadeordal, A. Suwa-Eisenmann, and T. Verdier. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Dimaranan, B. and R. McDougall, eds. 2005. Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 6 Data Base. West Lafayette, IN: Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Dobson, W. 2002. Shaping the Future of the North American Economic Space: A Framework for Action. Commentary no. 162, The Border Papers, C. D. Howe Institute. 821282128212821282128212. 2006. The Indian Elephant Sheds Its Past: The Implications for Canada. Commentary no. 235, C. D. Howe Institute. Estevadeordal, A. 2000. Negotiating Preferential Market Access: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement. Journal of World Trade 34 (1): 141-66. Estevadeordal, A. J. E. Lopez-Cordova, and K. Suominen. 2008. How Do Rules of Origin Affect Investment Flows Some Hypotheses and the Case of Mexico. In Gatekeepers of Global Commerce: Rules of Origin and International Economic Integration, edited by A. Estevadeordal and K. Suominen. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. Estevadeordal, A. and K. Suominen. 2008. What Are the Trade Effects of Rules of Origin In Gatekeepers of Global Commerce: Rules of Origin and International Economic Integration, edited by A. Estevadeordal and K. Suominen. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. Foot, D. K. 2007. Some Economic and Social Consequences of Population Aging. In A Canadian Priorities Agenda: Policy Choices to Improve Economic and Social Well-Being, edited by J. Leonard, C. Ragan, and F. St-Hilaire. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Georges, P. 2008a. Liberalizing NAFTA Rules of Origin: A Dynamic CGE Analysis. Review of International Economics 16 (4): 672-86. 821282128212821282128212. 2008b. Toward a North American Customs Union: Rules of Origin Liberalization Matters More Than a Common External Tariff for Canada. North American Journal of Economics and Finance 19: 304-18. 821282128212821282128212. 2010. Dispensing with NAFTA Rules of Origin Some Policy Options. The World Economy 33 (11): 1606-37. Georges, P. M. Merette, and A. Seckin. 2009. Should Canada Diversify Its Trade Pattern An Overlapping-Generations CGE Analysis of Trade and Ageing. Working paper 2009- 06, University of Ottawa. Ghosh, M. and S. Rao. 2005. A Canada-U. S. Customs Union: Potential Economic Impacts in NAFTA Countries. Journal of Policy Modeling 27: 805-27. Goldfarb, D. 2003. The Road to a Canada-U. S. Customs Union: Step-by-Step or in a Single Bound Commentary no. 184, The Border Papers, C. D. Howe Institute. 821282128212821282128212. 2006. Too Many Eggs in One Basket Evaluating Canada8217s Need to Diversify Trade. Commentary no. 236, C. D. Howe Institute. Harris, R. 2003. North American Linkage: Opportunities and Challenges for Canada. Calgary: Calgary University Press. Hart, M. 2002. A Trading Nation: Canadian Trade Policy from Colonialism to Globalization. Vancouver: UBC Press. 821282128212821282128212. 2007. Canadian Engagement in the Global Economy. In A Canadian Priorities Agenda: Policy Choices to Improve Economic and Social Well-Being, edited by J. Leonard, C. Ragan, and F. St-Hilaire. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Head, K. 2007. Engage the United States, Forget the Rest In A Canadian Priorities Agenda: Policy Choices to Improve Economic and Social Well-Being, edited by J. Leonard, C. Ragan, and F. St-Hilaire. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy. Heidrich, P. and D. Tussie. 2010. Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO: The Gyrating Wheels of Interdependence. In Redesigning the World Trade Organization for the Twenty - First Century, edited by D. P. Steger. Waterloo and Ottawa: CIGI, IDRC and Wilfrid Laurier University Press. Helliwell, J. 2002. Globalization and Well-Being. Vancouver: UBC Press. Helpman, E. and P. Krugman. 1985. Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hirschman, A. O. 1945. National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. 1969. Reprint, Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Krishna, K. 2005. Understanding Rules of Origin. Working paper no. 11150, NBER. Krugman, P. R. 1993. What Do Undergrads Need to Know About Trade AEA Papers and Proceedings, American Economic Review (May): 23-6. 821282128212821282128212. 1996. A Country is Not a Company. Harvard Business Review (January-February): 40-50. Kunimoto, R. and G. Sawchuk. 2005. NAFTA Rules of Origin. Discussion paper, Policy Research Initiative, Government of Canada. Lloyd, P. J. 1993. A Tariff Substitute for Rules of Origin in Free Trade Areas. The World Economy 16: 699-712. 821282128212821282128212. 2002. Country of Origin in the Global Economy. World Trade Review 1 (2): 171-85. Lloyd P. J. and X. G. Zhang. 2006. The Armington Model. Staff working paper, Productivity Commission, Melbourne. Lopez, R. A. 2005. Trade and Growth: Reconciling the Macroeconomic and Microeconomic Evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys 19 (4): 623-48. Mandel-Campbell, A. 2008. Foreign Investment Review Regimes: How Canada Stacks Up. The Conference Board of Canada Report on Trade, Investment Policy and International Cooperation (April). Meilke, K. J. Rude, and S. Zahniser. 2008. Is NAFTA Plus8217 an Option in the North American Agrifood Sector The World Economy 31: 925-46. Merette, M. and P. Georges. 2010. Demographic Changes and the Gains from Globalisation: An Analysis of Ageing, Capital Flows, and International Trade. Global Economy Journal, 10 (3), article 3. Panagariya, A. 2006. Transforming India. Paper presented at the conference India: An Emerging Giant, October 13-15, Columbia University, New York. Pastor, R. 2008. The Future of North America: Replacing a Bad Neighbor Policy. Foreign Affairs 87 (4): 84-98. Robson, W. B.P. 2007. Stuck on a Spoke: Proliferating Bilateral Trade Deals Are a Dangerous Game for Canada. C. D. Howe Institute e-Brief (August). United Nations Population Division. 2008. World Population Prospects: The 2006 Revision. esa. un. org. unpp. Viner, J. 1950. The Customs Union Issue. New York: Fondation Carnegie pour la paix internationale. Zhang X. G. 2006. Armington Elasticities and Terms of Trade Effects in Global CGE Models. Staff working paper, Productivity Commission, Melbourne. Commentary by John Curtis Patrick Georges and Marcel Mrette8217s study of Canada8217s strategic trade policy options in this era of slow US growth, rapid growth in many overseas markets and almost stalled global trade talks should reopen the debate on an important component of Canada8217s economic future. This debate, or versions of it, seems to occur whenever we are hit by an external shock such as the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846, the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, the Nixon Shock of 1971 and its aftermath, or the Great Recession of 200809. This debate occurs because involvement in the international economy has always been a key element of Canada8217s experience, due to its colonial heritage, its location next to the world8217s largest and most innovative economy, a large surplus of natural and food resources that are in demand around the world, and a relatively small population. And in most years, trade has contributed to Canada8217s economic growth and the per capita income of its residents. Yet all this is changing. Exports and imports are increasingly fragmented into intermediate or component goods and services that are part of local or global value chains and not necessarily bought or sold as final end-products. Frequently companies will choose to establish themselves abroad through investment (creating a foreign affiliate) rather than exporting or importing from a home base, which often means individuals from the home country have to go abroad to provide know-how, after-sales service or market intelligence. Increasingly, services are becoming the predominant international activity research and development (RampD), transportation, and the creation or implementation of new ideas and management techniques reflecting changes that have already taken form in the domestic economy. The operation of the international financial system exchange rate levels and, importantly, exchange rate volatility is becoming ever more important in determining what is traded internationally and by whom. This unpredictable activity increasingly and profoundly affects the cost of trading across borders. Additional provisions for security, ranging from more physical inspections to expensive electronic measures to verify shipments, are also increasing the cost of trade, magnifying the home bias of firm and company networks, and offsetting the often alluded to traditional benefits of trade. In the broader context, power is shifting steadily from the USA and Europe to parts of Asia, Latin America and Africa, which are geographically and at times culturally and legally distant from Canada and have mostly large, young populations, as Georges and Mrette highlight. The authors state or allude to some of these changes in context or in detail. While at times their focus is too hypothetical (for example, their ill-defined Canada-US customs union could be construed as a straw-man) or too focused on one dynamic, long-term factor (demographics), their study brings to our attention the fact that the trade world is changing, and that the wider discussion and debate about choices should also change. The changes affecting and influencing Canada will require the attention of politicians and policy-makers in various ways. The standard model of a free trade agreement like the North American Free Trade Agreement will have to be broadened and adjusted to reflect the realities of how trade actually is conducted in today8217s world. Governments will have to place more emphasis on policies affecting firms, especially at home for example, assisting them in overcoming information asymmetries in foreign markets tax policies financing and hedging costs to overcome volatility in exchange rates regulatory alignment with respect to food, health, and product safety standards and licensing requirements concerning highly technical products or professional competencies. In addition, emerging issues like climate change, and social considerations as they intersect with trade, will have to be researched, debated, and integrated into the world8217s economic regime so that it appropriately reflects the importance of these issues and the perceptions and interests of emerging economic powers and less advantaged peoples. More studies like this one will thus be needed as Canadians sort out domestically and internationally how to face the world in the first few decades of the 21st century. As always, the ultimate objective of all our efforts is to enhance our prosperity and well-being in a peaceful, predictable and more equitable world. Trade with a broader focus, with the old and new instruments and based on the tried-and-tested principles of nondiscrimination, transparency and a careful balance between the domestic social contract and international needs and opportunities, will help us achieve these objectives. John M. Curtis is a distinguished fellow at the Centre for International Governance Innovation (CIGI). He was the first chief economist at the Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade. He was also senior policy adviser and coordinator, trade and economic policy, and director of trade and economic analysis with that department. He also participated in the Canada-US free trade negotiations and the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations. Canada8217s Strategic Trade Policy Options


No comments:

Post a Comment